Imagine a society that felt: Because of how expensive it is to provide, there is no substantial benefit to publicly fund primary and secondary education, so anyone who wants such education must privately pay for it through personal savings or loans. Further, because of the expense, this education is not equally accessible to members of society and susceptible to wide variation in quality.
What is your reaction? I expect most feel that this view
undermines dignity and aspiration to the point of being cruel to individuals and
counterproductive to societies.
We think formal education is valuable to individual and collective well-being – up to a point. So much so that nations make it a legal requirement for citizens to attend formal education – up to a point. While effort is made to increase access and quality – up to a point.
That point is defined by cost-benefit analysis that incorporates the subtext of all discourse on education - money. The cost of providing education determines who pays for it, who has access to it, what quality is achieved, what content is covered, what level is required, how it is provided, how sector labour is treated, and much more.
Now, imagine that same society applied their views not to primary
and secondary, but to higher education (HE). What is your reaction?
I expect reactions tend to be mixed. Societies such as
Germany, Sweden, and Finland maintain that HE is a substantial value with
individual and societal benefits on par to those of primary and secondary
education. Accordingly, these HE systems are publicly funded to the point that
it is (virtually) free to attend – in the same sense that it is free to attend
primary and secondary schools. Other places such as Canada, the US and the
UK offer partial state funding for HE that requires significant private financing,
often in the form of personal savings or credit.
While we tend to exercise a firm collective grip on the
fiducial, functional, and financial expectations of primary and secondary education,
our grip becomes more flexible when the cost-benefit analysis moves to HE, as
evinced by the vicissitudes of systems like those in the US, UK, and Germany.
This post is directed at those societies with and without
some form of free HE, as it defends the claim: PSA is a viable means of
providing free HE that can help maximize education attainment levels.
No Such Thing As A Free Lunch
HE is not free. But for present purposes, “free HE” can be
defined as public education beyond secondary that is for students free of tuition
or expense, where the latter entails the former, but includes other costs such
as textbooks, school supplies, room and board, entertainment, and the like. This
is “free” in the sense that students do not have to use personal wealth or credit to fund their HE. Instead, like public primary and secondary education,
public HE is fully funded by tax dollars.
Within those societies that have a variety of free HE, the
subtext of money continues to have impact on HE discourse. For instance, in
Germany, because of the public cost to provide free HE, national placement
exams are used to determine who can study what. Since there is no such thing as
a free lunch, disagreement over free HE policies persist among taxpaying Germans, as it does among Americans and in other counties.
But no matter your view on the subject of free HE, the only
way to effectively immunize discourse against the subtext of money is to reduce
the financial burden in the first place. In such a circumstance, cash-weighted cost-benefit
analysis is eased, if not eliminated.
For some time now in the United States, including in the most recent Presidential election, there has been buzz about making at least some HE free. Various plans have been floated. For instance, Bernie Sanders wants to commit a further $48 billion a year to eliminate tuition and fees at four-year public colleges and universities, while he advocates cancellation of some $1.6 trillion in student loan debt through increased taxes. On both counts, the government has thus far failed to deliver.
Back in 2014, when President Obama was making similar
promises, I posted a response to one such
plan that made its way to the White House from the Lumina Foundation, dubbed
the F2CO – the free 2-year college option. This option aims at not just tuition-free but expense-free HE. Though the goal
is commendable, the F2CO plan is condemnable.
The response showed how PSA either corrects or avoids 14 shortcomings
of the F2CO plan. For my efforts, after publicly calling me a “laughable,
unstable, goofy guy,” I was Twitter-blocked by one of the F2CO authors, Professor
Sara Goldrick-Rab, of Temple University. So much for open, respectful
intellectual engagement with an employee of a publicly funded HEI.
Like every other free HE initiative, the F2CO plan offers no
reduction in system-wide costs, while it asks for additional public funding to,
in this case, make a mere 2-years of college free. PSA offers exactly the
opposite with a reduction in funding requirements, though it provides free public
HE for undergraduate and graduate studies in college and
university – among other numerous benefits unimaginable under the F2CO or any
other plan.
If the aim is tuition or expense-free HE in a system that is
less susceptible to the machinations, moods and markets that can loosen our
grip on the value of this pillar of society, then asking for more funding is an
irresponsible strategy. PSA asks for less, while it offers so much more. Though
this blog recently provided financial analyses of PSA for the Canadian and
Australian HE systems, the present discussion returns to an American financial analysis
from a previous post.
Relying on data that includes full time equivalent (FTE)
measures of student enrolment and academic staff, along with revenues and
expenditures of public higher education institutions (HEIs), analysis reveals
how the PSA model can be financed for far less than the HEI model of
universities and colleges. Sourced from the National Center for Education Statistics and the
College Board, all data is for the 2016-17 academic year and in constant 2017-18 USD.
The data is averaged across and not weighted for 2-year vs. 4-year institutions or
undergraduate vs. graduate level of study.
Full Time Equivalent Measures |
||
FTEs |
Student Ratio |
|
Faculty (FTEF) |
680,510 |
15.5 |
Graduate Assistants (FTEGA) |
98,599 |
107.2 |
Other Staff
(FTEOS) |
1,162,004 |
9.1 |
Students (FTES) |
10,565,751 |
N/A |
[Table 1: FTEF
includes instruction, research and public service. All graduate assistants are
considered part time. Figures are for 2 and 4-year public HEIs combined.
Source: Snyder, et al., 2019, pg. 262 and 283.]
Practice
Revenue Per FTEF |
||
Source |
Per
FTES |
Per
FTEF |
Revenue |
||
Total Revenue |
37,797 |
586,853 |
Appropriations & Non-operating Grants |
10,523 |
163,106 |
Tuition & Other Fees |
7,666 |
119,823 |
Expense |
||
Instructional |
10,832 |
167,896 |
Instructional, Research, Public Service, and
Academic Support |
18,959 |
293,864 |
Instructional, Research, Public Service,
Academic and Student Support |
21,036 |
326,058 |
[Table
2: Formula used in calculations: (Source per FTES) x (Ratio of FTES to FTEF
(15.5)) = Per FTEF (Practice Revenue). Source: Snyder, et al., 2019, pg.386,
387, 394.]
Because of the considerable liberty that a professional service model like PSA offers academics, there is no single formula that describes practice expenses. For instance, where teaching assistants are concerned, I don’t assign them work because, while I am happy to see students desperate for the money collect it, I prefer to do the work myself. Nevertheless, to make the case that PSA is financially viable, the following describes expenses for a solo practice situated in New York City, with office assistance and facilities, face-to-face teaching facilities, and a teaching/graduate assistant working 20 hours per week.
Professional Academic Practice Expenses |
|
Amount |
Item |
$10,000 |
Salary
of academic practitioner (gross) |
$3200 |
Salary of teaching
assistant (gross) |
$2000 |
Rent
(office and instruction services, facilities, and equipment) |
$200 |
Advertising, web hosting,
internet and phone fees |
$200 |
Office
supplies and equipment (computer, phone, printer, etc.) |
$50 |
General professional
liability insurance |
$300 |
Health
insurance |
$350 |
Retirement |
$500 |
Other
fees (society memberships, PD, conferences, etc.) |
$16,800 |
Total |
[Table 3]
Along with the qualifier regarding the effects of
professional liberty on practice expenses, it should be said that within an
established PSA HE system, there might well be policies that encourage opening
and offer support for operating a professional academic practice. For instance,
business incentives, tax breaks, group insurance rates, savings and investment perks,
facility leasing discounts, among other possibilities.
For these reasons, it is inappropriate to assess the
financial viability of the PSA proposal based solely on this sample practice profile.
Instead, the sample is used to signal financial liberty that the current HEI
model of universities and colleges cannot hope to match.
Consider that under PSA the operation of a private academic
practice for around $200,000 is 43% lower than the 2016-17 combined HEI expense
of instruction, research, public service, and academic support. Or consider that based solely on HEI instructional
expenses, every single FTEF in both the university and college systems earns an
annual gross income of $120,000 after practice expenses, which is 36% higher
than the 2020-21 systems-wide average of $88,277 for full time faculty (i.e.,
those faculty with 9-month employment contracts, which does not include
sessional faculty). Or finally, consider that the average
stipend of $18,616 paid to HEI graduate employee types – teaching assistant,
research assistant and graduate assistant – is less than half that offered by PSA, which also manages to adjustment the FTEGA-to-student
ratio from 107.2 to 15.5, on par with the FTEF ratio.[see Table 1]
No matter how it’s sliced, even if PSA can only reduce the total cost of HE by 30 or 40 percent, this is a significant financial improvement, with numerous benefits to individuals and societies.
[NOTE: I am working on a post that presents the real total
cost of HE. That is, not only the expenses typically reported by HEIs, but also
those associated with: the operation of accreditation boards, the bureaucracies
of the federal and state Departments of Finance and Education, federal student
aid and debt management, tax breaks, education savings incentives, HEI
investment losses, interest paid on general bonds, union representation, and
more. Most of these real costs are eliminated or reduced by the PSA model.]
While it reduces costs, PSA continues to facilitate
traditional face-to-face education, but in a model where both students and
teachers (academics) are personally invested in the satisfactory completion of
courses and credentials. This is so thanks to model features such as anonymous,
crowd-source evaluation of students and public service performance data of academics. With
such quality assurance mechanisms in place, a professional academic has far
less room (and HEIs have none) to manufacture learning outcomes and so must
provide effective quality education, a record of which is available to all who
seek their services. A reliable Yelp for HE.
None of the proposals for free HE can hope to accomplish
what PSA does, because without exception these proposals assume the HEI model.
This means there will be no reduction in costs, but rather an increase. With
uncertain success, cost-benefit campaigns might be launched in the hope of persuading
taxpayers to give new money or to channel existing money away from other social
goods such as healthcare, welfare, or primary and secondary education. For
instance, HEIs can cite how their contributions to the economy offset costs and
offer a wide range of benefits.
But here it is important to restate a fundamental
distinction between HEIs and HE. Universities and colleges are not HE. The oft
cited contributions come from HE, not these institutional middlemen which are
merely one means of facilitation. PSA also facilitates the full spectrum of
activity referred to as HE, though with far less cost and greater benefit.
However, if wholesale adoption of PSA seems unreasonable,
then consider a more modest proposal. In a model with widespread financial strain, Liberal Arts and Humanities programmes are routinely obliged to justify their
value to students and societies, as they face declines in funding and enrolment.
Recognizing that there is no such thing as a free lunch, PSA
at least offers a very inexpensive one that frees Liberal Arts and Humanities
from the financially strained cost-benefit analysis discourse of the HEI model,
allowing their contributions to HE to be more readily received by students and
societies. Consider how in fields of study (FOS) like those found in Liberal
Arts and Humanities, using only select expenses or the tuition and fees of HEIs,
it is possible to operate a private professional academic practice not only in
America but also Canada and Australia.
Country |
Source |
Amount (CND and AUD) |
Practice Income (gross) |
Canada |
Tuition & Fees (average domestic (under)graduate per
FTES) |
$11,420 |
$199,850 |
Tuition & Fees (average domestic undergraduate per FTES in PSA amenable FOS) |
$8,071 |
$141,242 |
|
Australia |
Tuition & Fees (total for international students only) |
$9,222,983,000 |
$185,007 |
Average
Unit Teaching Expense per FTES (10 classroom-based undergraduate FOS) |
$16,000 |
$363,200 |
Whether it’s wholesale or partial substitution, these
financial analyses substantiate the claim that PSA is a viable means of
providing free HE. To emphasize just one substantiation, consider that in
Australia, even if the teaching expense per FTES is cut in half, this provides
each and every full-time equivalent faculty (academic) with $181,600 in practice
revenue per year.
The effects of such cost reduction on HE discourse are
profound and discussed throughout this blog. But to close this section, one effect
of note is on the quarrel over student loan debt forgiveness. Reducing the total
cost of HE by 40, 50, or even 70 percent can not only make free public HE a
reality but eliminate the need for future student loans, giving those in opposition
to debt forgiveness reason to reconsider.
No Such Thing As Too Much Education
As finances of the HEI model sculpt HE discourse, we find
notions like degree inflation, overeducation, oversupply, labour demands, and return
on investment that shape cost-benefit analysis claims such as: i) There are more PhDs
than we need to achieve the economic goals of society; or ii) Based on expected
lifetime earnings, some fields of study are a risky investment.
Take as an example, my field of philosophy. The predictable question arises: “What are you gonna do with a philosophy degree?” HEI websites provide answers that reassure few who ask this question. The mindset is that a PhD in philosophy meets neither the public economic expectations of a society nor the private investment expectations of an individual. Along with virtually any degree outside of science and business, it is a field of study discouraged by parents who fear their darling doctor of philosophy will end up an overeducated, underpaid barista.
Fair enough within the expensive HEI model, where American student
debt has now reached $1.7 trillion. But
under the PSA model the response is, “So what? Certainly, being a CEO or a
surgeon is not for everyone, but we should welcome a world where it is possible
to have highly educated citizens in all walks of life.”
These polar responses are framed by the disparate financial
realities of the two models. Since PSA is a viable alternative that dramatically
reduces HE costs, “overeducated” and “oversupply” are not pressed into the PSA
discourse. There is no financially fueled concern with “too much education” or
“useless education.” Without regret we can have a world filled with highly
educated baristas.
Thanks to the long and expensive tenure of the HEI model,
this might be hard to imagine – perhaps as hard as it is to imagine HE without
university and college institutions, though historically this was in fact the case.
At the same time, think of people like Elon Musk working on ways to make
seamless interfaces between man and machine, where knowledge is internally democratized:
I know what you know and we both know everything. Supposing this access was
available to all at low to no cost, would any of us have a serious challenge to
such a world? What objections could be launched against a barista with
knowledge beyond the current aspirations of any PhD in philosophy or biology or
law or….? Beyond personal preferences, would any of us think such access “too
much” or “useless”?
Elsewhere this blog has addressed possible technological trumps of traditional modes of knowledge
transfer – which notably is not the same as education. But no matter the means –
be it new technology or new model – the end of increased access to knowledge and education is unassailable. A
little knowledge is indeed a dangerous thing.
Of course, the need to generate new knowledge continues and
HE is a key player in this valuable social good. Recognizing that universities
and colleges are not HE and reducing the total cost of HE facilitation, the PSA
model liberates substantial public funds that can be channeled to increase
research production on a scale and scope not possible in the HEI model – not to
mention the increase in human capital that PSA makes possible.
In closing, lest it be thought there is no need for everyone
to have access to HE or that entrance exams can successfully select those
individuals for whom HE will provide the most personal and public benefit,
consider these observations:
Nor is there much confidence in processes that supposedly select for valuable human capital. A study of one of the more demanding national college entrance exams in the world, China’s gaokao, reveals that its top scorers have not made more significant contributions to society than have those without top scores [note link is in Chinese]. Another study found that those with higher gaokao scores are less likely to be entrepreneurs that open innovative businesses. The authors hypothesize that this is because preparation for the gaokao produces students that are less socially adept, more risk aversive, and lack jack-of-all-trades skills.
In the final analysis, casting a wide net to capture and
cultivate human capital is the best practice – up to a point. Compared to the
expensive HEI model, PSA can afford to move this point much farther.
Second, it might also be argued that in the United States
and elsewhere there are too many HEIs servicing declining enrolments. Ignoring that some 32 million Americans have yet to finish the degrees they started, this is a risky response to fluctuations in
college-age enrolment trends.
It suggests education is for the young and not something to
be valued throughout life. It requires the complex, fixed education
infrastructure of the HEI model to expand and contract in response to
demographics, rather than market demand, which are not the same thing. But perhaps
more importantly, there is no guarantee that after the dust settles the best
teachers and researchers will be the ones left employed by the remaining
institutions. Thanks to the poor working conditions and compensation of the HEI
model, this isn’t even true now when there are perhaps too many HEIs, because a
lot of talent leaves academia to pursue careers that are more satisfactory on many
measures.
The private practice, entrepreneurial nature of PSA means it
can more easily expand and contract according to demands associated not only
with demographics, but also industry, interest, and location. At the same time,
the oversight provided by professional licensure and the aforementioned Yelp-style
evaluation mechanisms, means that academics who provide poor service will
either need to seek professional development or fail to make a living in the
profession. As for making a living, as indicated, the PSA model offers working
conditions and compensation that can serve to attract rather than alienate would-be
academics in large numbers.
Third, recall the imagined views on primary and secondary
education that opened this post and how most people would find them
unacceptable. In fact, most societies consider access to education a human
right, as evinced by international and national rights documents that call for equal,
free access to primary and secondary education. What many people do not realize is that access to HE is also a human right. The
International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights is ratified by 171
members of the United Nations ranging from the
United States to China.
Article 13, sections 2 (c) and (e) state:
Higher education shall be made equally accessible
to all, on the basis of capacity, by every appropriate means, and in particular
by the progressive introduction of free education; and [the] development of a
system of schools at all levels shall be actively pursued, an adequate
fellowship system shall be established, and the material conditions of teaching
staff shall be continuously improved.
As such, access to (higher) education is not about what individuals
or societies expect as a return on investment, it is not about finance-based cost-benefit
analysis. The extravagant cost of the HEI model has twisted discourse in this
direction and the lack of an alternative service model has made it seem
unavoidable.
But it is avoidable. Along with earlier ones, this post has argued that PSA is an appropriate means of HE provision that
offers real progress toward free HE as it stands to maximize the education levels
across society.
No comments:
Post a Comment