Wednesday, February 2, 2022

Historical Roots of the PSA Model – Part 2

In revealing the historical roots of PSA, part one of this series looked to the emergence of higher education in 12th century Italy, where, “Emphatically, Bologna was a student university…” (Haskins, 1923). The final installment of the series looks at its professional pedigree in the 19th and 20th centuries; while this second post looks to Paris, France, for the medieval choreography of confluence and conflict that produced modern higher education institutions (HEIs). With power dynamics adjusted through economic and political maneuvering, Paris adds momentum to the shift in higher education (HE) from individuals to institutions – a shift that PSA aims to reverse.

Continuing to rely on the Medieval expertise of Haskins’, The Rise of Universities, we find that, “In northern Europe the origin of universities must be sought at Paris, in the cathedral school of Notre-Dame” (Haskins, 1923).

Notre-Dame
In an institutional sense the university [of Paris] was a direct outgrowth of the school of Notre-Dame, whose chancellor alone had authority to license teaching in the diocese and thus kept his control over the granting of university degrees, which here as at Bologna were originally teachers’ certificates. The early schools were within the cathedral precincts on the Ile de la Cité, that tangled quarter about Notre-Dame pictured by Victor Hugo which has long since been demolished.

In [1200], after certain students had been killed in a town and gown altercation, King Philip Augustus issued a formal privilege which punished his prévôt [provost or royal police chief] and recognized the exemption of the students and their servants from lay jurisdiction… [This was followed by] the first papal privilege, the bull Parens scientiarum of 1231, issued after a two years’ cessation of lectures growing out of a riot in which a band of students, having found “wine that was good and sweet to drink,” beat up the tavern keeper and his friends till they in turn suffered from the prévôt and his men…. Confirming the existing exemptions, the Pope goes on to regulate the discretion of the chancellor in conferring the license, at the same time that he recognizes the right of the masters and students “to make constitutions and ordinances regulating the manner and time of lectures and disputations, the costume [or gown] to be worn [by masters and students],” attendance at masters’ funerals, the lectures of bachelors, … the price of lodgings, and the coercion [or hazing] of members.

While the word university does not appear in these documents, it is taken for granted. A university in the sense of an organized body of masters existed already in the twelfth century; by 1231 it had developed into a corporation, for Paris, in contrast to Bologna, was a university of masters.

In a city of powerful people like chancellors vested with church authority and provosts who protected monarch interests, we find in these passages further evidence of the considerable influence that masters and scholars enjoyed. The studium generale – as the amalgam of master and student universitates or corporations was called – brought prestige to the city and its authorities, supported the economy across a range of industries, and provided personnel for the bureaucracies of church and monarchy.

Precisely because of this, papal and royal interest in HE intensified, as did the occurrence of conflict among the interested parties. Though without the drunken violence common to student and townsfolk clashes, one quarrel of note during this time occurred between masters and chancellors. As chancellors of Notre-Dame attempted to exercise more control over the who, what and how of education, masters resisted and tensions grew until finally a group left for the monasteries in what became known as the Latin Quarter of Paris – so called after their migration and language of instruction. Here masters were outside the direct control of the chancellor, allowing them greater autonomy in the practice of their profession.

 

College Employers

With the passage of time, there were gains and losses in the power struggles among scholar, master, pope, and king. During the 12th and the 13th centuries, there were two introductions that substantially determined the distribution of power we now consider native to HE: corporeal colleges and salaried lectureships.

Another university institution which goes back to twelfth-century Paris is the college. Originally merely an endowed hospice or hall of residence, the college early became an established unit of academic life at many universities. “The object of the earliest college-founders was simply to secure board and lodging for poor scholars who could not pay for it themselves;” but in course of time the colleges became normal centres of life and teaching, absorbing into themselves much of the activity of the university. The colleges had buildings and endowments, if the university had not. …But of course the ultimate home of the college was Oxford and Cambridge, where it came to be the most characteristic feature of university life, arrogating to itself practically all teaching as well as direction of social life, until the university [universitas] became merely an examining and degree-conferring body.

Sorbonne - University of Paris
Quite naturally Paris became the source and the model for northern universities. Oxford branched off from this parent stem late in the twelfth century, …Cambridge began somewhat later. The German universities, none of them older than the fourteenth century, were confessed imitations of Paris.

In the first post of this series, Zuddas (2019) was used to emphasize that “spatial tactics” are essential to institutional identity. In architecture, space can be analyzed through function, location and duration. The introduction of customary college buildings instituted exclusive function and intransience of location and duration. Though not much of these early college structures remain throughout Europe and at the time they might have seemed a prudent measure, imperceptibly the identity of HE had changed. It was no longer a university of masters and scholars, but a corporation of edifices and endowments - a campus, fixed in function, location, and duration.

As a spatial tactic in identity construction, the establishment of these colleges helped to immunize papal and royal authorities from the threat of collective boycotts, strikes and migrations which had empowered masters and scholars. The college issued not only corporeal forms and facilities, but also prescriptions and proscriptions. The college was shaping into a factory that could be conveniently overseen, from which one required permission to enter, and from which one could be expelled – expelled from HE itself.

As the first post of this series indicates, PSA identity spatial tactics recommend dispersion of HE throughout a community – a true community campus. At the same time, conversion of customary campuses to facility and service vendors for professional academics in independent practice is also possible.  Dispersion or conversion can relieve some private pain points related to the restrictive spatial tactics of the current HEI model. Students often need to move far from home and loved ones to receive HE that is consequently more expensive, while academics are frequently forced to accept faculty positions apart from their spouses or abandon career aspirations to accommodate those of their spouses. Greater freedom to choose where one offers and receives HE can help to relieve such personal hardships.

Additionally, as will be discussed in a moment, dispersion or conversion reduces the total cost of the HE system. PSA has developed practice prospectuses for various locations - from small to large cities in developed and developing countries. In every case, PSA is at least 50% and often 70-80% cheaper to operate than the HEI model – while it increases academic income, reduces student expense, and improves education quality. Comparatively, the medieval introduction of college campuses was an unfortunate misguided tactic.

A second important shift in power came with salaried lectureships. As we have seen, originally Bologna was an intimate exchange between individuals, where scholars paid masters for their education services, giving students an upper hand in the power dynamics. As Haskins (1923) says, “[T]he masters lived at first wholly from the fees of their pupils.” However, the swelling economic and political benefits associated with HE encouraged papal and royal authorities to attract and retain masters within their jurisdictions – a continued practice that results in brain drain. To this end, the salaried lectureship became a key incentive. An informative account of the use of this incentive is offered by Cobban (1985).

Salaried university lectureships probably made their first appearance at the Castilian university of Palencia, where, by a bull of Horonius III of 1220, Ferdinand III of Castile was authorised to use part of the diocesan tithes for payment of masters at the university for a period of five years, a grant which was renewed by the papacy for a further quinquennium in 1225. In 1224 the Emperor Frederick II set out to attract eminent [masters] to his new University of Naples by offering privileges and what were almost certainly salaries (“donaria”). Salaried lectureships were envisaged from the start at Toulouse University created by Gregory IX…[where] by a treaty arrangement of 1229, Count Raymond VII of Toulouse undertook to pay the salaries of a number of lecturers for ten years, although the papacy had to pressurise the count into honouring his pledge.

Instituted by the communes and with the general, though not at the outset universal, support of the lecturing staff, municipally endowed lectureships were devised as a means of securing and retaining prominent teachers and of countering some of the excesses of the student power movement which, radiating outwards from Bologna, had become entrenched in the majority of the Italian universities in the course of the thirteenth century. …From the beginnings the salaried lectureship took progressive root throughout the universities of southern Europe and, from the late fourteenth century, it penetrated the northern university scene… In the sixteenth century most universities had come to operate with a considerable quota of salaried lectureships, and the original system of payment by student fees was largely superseded.

The growth of the salaried lectureship in all its kaleidoscopic manifestations helped to promote a deeper sense of cohesion and professional status among Europe’s university lecturers and did much to relieve them of the vagaries of a livelihood dependent upon student fees.

[The] salaried lectureship brought with it the concept of tenure which, above all, transformed the profession of university teacher from one of minimal security to one wherein longer-term career prospects were realisable…

Cobban’s detailed description of this capacity building tool is worth comprehensive exploration in another post. He reveals multi-tiered tenure systems, elaborate selection processes, substitute lecturer networks, examples of corruption, and more. For now, it is enough to focus on select aspects that instruct the PSA model.

Obviously, along with this change in the economics of HE came changes in the power dynamics. Though students exercised some level of participation in the selection of candidates for salaried lectureship positions, their influence over the conditions of service from masters and townsfolk was waning. What solidarity existed in the universitas societas magistrorum discipulorumque was fading, since now when students might threaten to leave the city with purse in hand, their masters might be less inclined to follow. While Cobban seems to characterize the introduction of salaried lectureships as an improvement in the professional lives of masters, the fact is that the who, how, what, and where of their labour were now subject to the capricious control of cross and crown purses – being delivered from student excesses to saint and sovereign estrangement.

Increasingly at this stage in the emergence of modern universities, if you desired a career in HE you were selected and salaried by higher authorities that also founded and financed the colleges within which you were affixed in the provision of your expert services. Outside of this nascent institutional employment arrangement, which matured into the modern HEI model, there was diminishing hope of earning a respectable living as an independent master.

 

PSA Responses

PSA is an attempt to calibrate the power gauges in HE. Given the history that has been provided here, it should come as no surprise that it does so through two key features of the model - its economics and politics.

In terms of economics, PSA liberates HE from the financial burden imposed by the modern HEI model of universities and colleges with their bloated administrations and campuses, thereby dramatically reducing the public and private burden to fund HE. As PSA private practice models and HE system public financial data demonstrate, there is substantial money to be saved. Consider that in the US with a full-time equivalent faculty of 680,510 and a full-time equivalent student body of 10,565,751, if the reported institutional revenue from tuition and others fees ($80,997,047,166) or the reported expense of instruction ($114,448,214,832) was paid directly to academics offering their services under the protection and direction of a professional academic society, they could respectively earn respectable incomes of $119,024 and $168,180. These figures represent 20% of the total revenue and 28.5% of the total expenses reported by public HEIs for the 2016-17 academic year in constant 2017-18 USD. See the table below for possible existing HEI model funding sources of PSA:

Source

Per FTES

Total FTES

Per FTEF

Revenue

Total Revenue

$37,797

$399,353,690,547

$586,844

Appropriations & Non-operating Grants

$10,523

$111,183,397,773

$163,382

Tuition & Other Fees

$7,666

$80,997,047,166

$119,024

Expense

Instructional

$10,832

$114,448,214,832

$168,120

Instructional, Research, Public Service, and Academic Support

$18,959

$200,316,073,209

$294,361

Instructional, Research, Public Service, Academic and Student Support

$21,036

$222,261,138,036

$326,609

[Formula used in calculations: (Source per FTES) x (Total FTES) ÷ (Total FTEF) = Per FTEF (Practice Funding/Revenue). Source: Snyder, et al., 2019, pg.386, 387, 394.]

With this sort of systemic financial liberation and practice revenue, academics (or masters, in the Medieval vernacular) could once again offer their education services directly to students, in the absence of expensive HEI middlemen.

In terms of politics, PSA liberates HE from the oversight burden imposed by the modern HEI model of universities and colleges with its unnecessary interference in the education relationship, thereby bringing teachers and students back to more intimate, mutually beneficial relationships sustained through professional society and private academic practice. The third installment of this series will explore the professional society roots of PSA in greater detail, so for now a sketch will suffice.

The professional society, like its gild or universitas predecessors, enjoys the same legal status as a modern university or college – that is, a corporation in the original Roman sense of the term. It is not a physical entity, but an abstract relational one. However, unlike a modern HEI, it does not employ its members, but licenses, disciplines and develops its members in the collective and individual provision of their expert services to the public. This is the established form of self-oversight for professions that offer services with at least as much social value as HE, such as medicine, law, psychiatry, engineering, and dentistry.

Combining economics and politics, consider that, as of July 2019, the State Bar of California, founded in 1927 by the California Legislature, services the general public and over 270,000 licentiates. It accomplishes this with a staff of 583, at an annual expense of $164.1 million USD and a staff to member ratio of 1:463. It seems inconceivable that a university or college could operate with these numbers, not to mention with the addition of the oversight provided by accreditation boards, all of which is made redundant by PSA.


In anticipation of Part 3 of this series, consider the sketch provided here of a modern legislatively sanctioned Professional Society of Academics (PSA) as Haskins (1923) contrasts the masters of then and now.

If, as some reformers maintain, the social position and self-respect of professors involve their management of university affairs, the Middle Ages were the great age of professorial control. The university itself was a society of masters when it was not a society of students. As there were no endowments of importance there were no boards of trustees, nor was there any such system of state control as exists on the Continent or in many parts of the United States. Administration in the modern sense was strikingly absent, but much time was consumed in various sorts of university meetings. In a quite remarkable degree the university was self-governing as well as self-respecting, escaping some of the abuses of a system which occasionally allows trustees or regents to speak of professors as their “hired men.” Whether the individual professor was freer under such a system is another question, for the corporation of masters was apt to exercise a pretty close control over action if not over opinion, and the tyranny of colleagues is a form of that “tyranny of one’s next-door neighbor” from which the world seems unable to escape.

Fair enough, but if tyranny there must be then let us choose our tyrant. More than that, if the PSA model is viable, then the price of self-inflicted tyranny purchases numerous benefits for not only academics but students and society at large. This blog is devoted to demonstrating those benefits, which include: respectable remuneration for academics and their assistants, reduced educational cost for students, financial liberation for all parties, responsible education service, improved education standards, expansion of academic service providers, expansion of access to HE for domestic and international students, improved mobility for academics and students, and more.

Through the passage of time, the intimate, economic, political, and education relationships between teacher and student have been subordinated to the interests of HEIs, with their concentrated campuses, exploitive employment, corporate sponsorship, high cost, and state neglect. But the HEI model is unsustainable, unresponsive, and unnecessary, as history and PSA have shown.

This is not to say that the PSA model is perfect. The claim is only that it is superior to the HEI model we have inherited. As always, I invite comment on this claim and collaboration in its confirmation.

 

References

Cobban, A. R. (Spring 1985). "Elective Salaried Lectureships in the Universities of Southern Europe in the Pre-Reformation Era." Bulletin of the John Rylands Library of Manchester. Vol. 67.2: pp. 662-687.

Haskins, C H. (1923). The Rise of Universities. New York: Henry Holt and Company.

Snyder, T. D., de Brey, C., Dillow, S.A. (2019). Digest of education statistics 2017 (NCES 2018-070). Washington, DCNational Center for Education Statistics.

Zuddas, F. (2019). The Project of Universality. In Chipperfield, D., Duplantier, M., et al. (eds.) HEC Campus: evolution of a model (pp. 162-220). Zurich: Park Books.

No comments:

Post a Comment

FEATURED POST

Historical Roots of the PSA Model – Part 1

When people first learn of PSA, they tend to view it as something without precedent. It is not. Like most “new” ideas, it is merely a mix of...

POPULAR POSTS